Specific factors model

Содержание

Слайд 2

Chapter Organization Introduction The Specific Factors Model International Trade in the

Chapter Organization

Introduction
The Specific Factors Model
International Trade in the Specific Factors Model
Income

Distribution and the Gains from Trade
Political Economy of Trade: A Preliminary View
International Labor Mobility
Summary
Слайд 3

Introduction If trade is so good for the economy, why is

Introduction

If trade is so good for the economy, why is there

such opposition?
Two main reasons why international trade has strong effects on the distribution of income within a country:
Resources cannot move immediately or costlessly from one industry to another.
Industries differ in the factors of production they demand.
Слайд 4

The Specific Factors Model The specific factors model allows trade to

The Specific Factors Model

The specific factors model allows trade to affect

income distribution.
Assumptions of the model:
Two goods, cloth and food.
Three factors of production: labor (L), capital (K) and land (T for terrain).
Perfect competition prevails in all markets.
Слайд 5

The Specific Factors Model (cont.) Cloth produced using capital and labor

The Specific Factors Model (cont.)

Cloth produced using capital and labor (but

not land).
Food produced using land and labor (but not capital).
Labor is a mobile factor that can move between sectors.
Land and capital are both specific factors used only in the production of one good.
Слайд 6

The Specific Factors Model (cont.) How much of each good does

The Specific Factors Model (cont.)

How much of each good does the

economy produce?
The production function for cloth gives the quantity of cloth that can be produced given any input of capital and labor:
QC = QC (K, LC) (4-1)
QC is the output of cloth
K is the capital stock
LC is the labor force employed in cloth
Слайд 7

The Specific Factors Model (cont.) The production function for food gives

The Specific Factors Model (cont.)

The production function for food gives the

quantity of food that can be produced given any input of land and labor:
QF = QF (T, LF) (4-2)
QF is the output of food
T is the supply of land
LF is the labor force employed in food
Слайд 8

Production Possibilities How does the economy’s mix of output change as

Production Possibilities

How does the economy’s mix of output change as labor

is shifted from one sector to the other?
When labor moves from food to cloth, food production falls while output of cloth rises.
Figure 4-1 illustrates the production function for cloth.
Слайд 9

Fig. 4-1: The Production Function for Cloth

Fig. 4-1: The Production Function for Cloth

Слайд 10

Production Possibilities (cont.) The shape of the production function reflects the

Production Possibilities (cont.)

The shape of the production function reflects the law

of diminishing marginal returns.
Adding one worker to the production process (without increasing the amount of capital) means that each worker has less capital to work with.
Therefore, each additional unit of labor adds less output than the last.
Figure 4-2 shows the marginal product of labor, which is the increase in output that corresponds to an extra unit of labor.
Слайд 11

Fig. 4-2: The Marginal Product of Labor

Fig. 4-2: The Marginal Product of Labor

Слайд 12

Production Possibilities (cont.) For the economy as a whole, the total

Production Possibilities (cont.)

For the economy as a whole, the total labor

employed in cloth and food must equal the total labor supply:
LC + LF = L (4-3)
Use these equations to derive the production possibilities frontier of the economy.
Слайд 13

Production Possibilities (cont.) Use a four-quadrant diagram to construct production possibilities

Production Possibilities (cont.)

Use a four-quadrant diagram to construct production possibilities frontier

in Figure 4-3.
Lower left quadrant indicates the allocation of labor.
Lower right quadrant shows the production function for cloth from Figure 4-1.
Upper left quadrant shows the corresponding production function for food.
Upper right quadrant indicates the combinations of cloth and food that can be produced.
Слайд 14

Fig. 4-3: The Production Possibility Frontier in the Specific Factors Model

Fig. 4-3: The Production Possibility Frontier in the Specific Factors Model

Слайд 15

Production Possibilities (cont.) Why is the production possibilities frontier curved? Diminishing

Production Possibilities (cont.)

Why is the production possibilities frontier curved?
Diminishing returns to

labor in each sector cause the opportunity cost to rise when an economy produces more of a good.
Opportunity cost of cloth in terms of food is the slope of the production possibilities frontier – the slope becomes steeper as an economy produces more cloth.
Слайд 16

Production Possibilities (cont.) Opportunity cost of producing one more yard of

Production Possibilities (cont.)

Opportunity cost of producing one more yard of cloth

is MPLF/MPLC pounds of food.
To produce one more yard of cloth, you need 1/MPLC hours of labor.
To free up one hour of labor, you must reduce output of food by MPLF pounds.
To produce less food and more cloth, employ less in food and more in cloth.
The marginal product of labor in food rises and the marginal product of labor in cloth falls, so MPLF/MPLC rises.
Слайд 17

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation How much labor is employed in

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation

How much labor is employed in each

sector?
Need to look at supply and demand in the labor market.
Demand for labor:
In each sector, employers will maximize profits by demanding labor up to the point where the value produced by an additional hour equals the marginal cost of employing a worker for that hour.
Слайд 18

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.) The demand curve for labor

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.)

The demand curve for labor in

the cloth sector:
MPLC x PC = w (4-4)
The wage equals the value of the marginal product of labor in manufacturing.
The demand curve for labor in the food sector:
MPLF x PF = w (4-5)
The wage equals the value of the marginal product of labor in food.
Слайд 19

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.) Figure 4-4 represents labor demand

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.)

Figure 4-4 represents labor demand in

the two sectors.
The demand for labor in the cloth sector is MPLC from Figure 4-2 multiplied by PC.
The demand for labor in the food sector is measured from the right.
The horizontal axis represents the total labor supply L.
Слайд 20

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.) The two sectors must pay

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.)

The two sectors must pay the

same wage because labor can move between sectors.
If the wage were higher in the cloth sector, workers would move from making food to making cloth until the wages become equal.
Or if the wage were higher in the food sector, workers would move in the other direction.
Where the labor demand curves intersect gives the equilibrium wage and allocation of labor between the two sectors.
Слайд 21

Fig. 4-4: The Allocation of Labor

Fig. 4-4: The Allocation of Labor

Слайд 22

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.) At the production point, the

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.)

At the production point, the production

possibility frontier must be tangent to a line whose slope is minus the price of cloth divided by that of food.
Relationship between relative prices and output:
-MPLF/MPLC = -PC/PF (4-6)
Слайд 23

Fig. 4-5: Production in the Specific Factors Model

Fig. 4-5: Production in the Specific Factors Model

Слайд 24

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.) What happens to the allocation

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.)

What happens to the allocation of

labor and the distribution of income when the prices of food and cloth change?
Two cases:
An equal proportional change in prices
A change in relative prices
Слайд 25

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.) When both prices change in

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.)

When both prices change in the

same proportion, no real changes occur.
The wage rate (w) rises in the same proportion as the prices, so real wages (i.e., the ratios of the wage rate to the prices of goods) are unaffected.
The real incomes of capital owners and landowners also remain the same.
Слайд 26

Fig. 4-6: An Equal-Proportional Increase in the Prices of Cloth and Food

Fig. 4-6: An Equal-Proportional Increase in the Prices of Cloth and

Food
Слайд 27

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.) When only PC rises, labor

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.)

When only PC rises, labor shifts

from the food sector to the cloth sector and the output of cloth rises while that of food falls.
The wage rate (w) does not rise as much as PC since cloth employment increases and thus the marginal product of labor in that sector falls.
Слайд 28

Fig. 4-7: A Rise in the Price of Cloth

Fig. 4-7: A Rise in the Price of Cloth

Слайд 29

Fig. 4-8: The Response of Output to a Change in the Relative Price of Cloth

Fig. 4-8: The Response of Output to a Change in the

Relative Price of Cloth
Слайд 30

Fig. 4-9: Determination of Relative Prices

Fig. 4-9: Determination of Relative Prices

Слайд 31

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.) Relative Prices and the Distribution

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.)

Relative Prices and the Distribution of

Income
Suppose that PC increases by 10%. Then, the wage would rise by less than 10%.
What is the economic effect of this price increase on the incomes of the following three groups?
Workers, owners of capital, and owners of land
Слайд 32

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.) Owners of capital are definitely

Prices, Wages, and Labor Allocation (cont.)

Owners of capital are definitely better

off.
Landowners are definitely worse off.
Workers: cannot say whether workers are better or worse off:
Depends on the relative importance of cloth and food in workers’ consumption.
Слайд 33

Trade and Relative Prices The relative price of cloth prior to

Trade and Relative Prices
The relative price of cloth prior to trade

is determined by the intersection of the economy’s relative supply of cloth and its relative demand.
Free trade relative price of cloth is determined by the intersection of world relative supply of cloth and world relative demand.
Opening up to trade increases the relative price of cloth in an economy whose relative supply of cloth is larger than for the world as a whole.

International Trade in the Specific Factors Model

Слайд 34

Fig. 4-10: Trade and Relative Prices

Fig. 4-10: Trade and Relative Prices

Слайд 35

International Trade in the Specific Factors Model (cont.) Gains from trade

International Trade in the Specific Factors Model (cont.)

Gains from trade
Without trade,

the economy’s output of a good must equal its consumption.
International trade allows the mix of cloth and food consumed to differ from the mix produced.
The country cannot spend more than it earns:
PC x DC + PF x DF = PC x QC +PF x QF
Слайд 36

International Trade in the Specific Factors Model (cont.) The economy as

International Trade in the Specific Factors Model (cont.)

The economy as a

whole gains from trade.
It imports an amount of food equal to the relative price of cloth times the amount of cloth exported:
DF - QF = (PC / PF) x (QC – DC )
It is able to afford amounts of cloth and food that the country is not able to produce itself.
The budget constraint with trade lies above the production possibilities frontier in Figure 4-11.